首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   275篇
  免费   7篇
  2020年   3篇
  2019年   4篇
  2018年   3篇
  2017年   7篇
  2016年   10篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   4篇
  2013年   121篇
  2012年   4篇
  2011年   7篇
  2009年   3篇
  2008年   3篇
  2007年   4篇
  2006年   4篇
  2005年   2篇
  2004年   1篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   2篇
  2000年   3篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   2篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   4篇
  1992年   2篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   2篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   6篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   2篇
  1983年   7篇
  1982年   2篇
  1981年   5篇
  1980年   4篇
  1979年   5篇
  1978年   5篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   3篇
  1975年   2篇
  1974年   3篇
  1972年   1篇
  1971年   2篇
  1970年   1篇
  1967年   1篇
  1962年   1篇
排序方式: 共有282条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
91.
In the West, public space ideally serves as the open, transformative core of urban democratic society. But what role does it play in a non-Western democracy with anti-individualist, authoritarian cultural mores, such as in Japan? The author used archival research, direct observations and informal interviews, as well as reference to key insights of actor-network theory (ANT) to investigate whether or not the public spaces of a Japanese suburb are conducive to individual freedom and expression. The paper concludes that these spaces help maintain what Sugimoto (1997) calls the “friendly authoritarianism” of Japanese society.  相似文献   
92.
Book Reviews     
H. Roger Grant and Charles W. Bohi. The Country Railroad Station in America. Sioux Falls, S.D.: Augustana College, Center for Western Studies, 1988, 192 pp. Julius K. Hunter. Westmoreland and Portland Places: The History ana Architecture of America's Premier Private Streets, 1888-1988. Columbia: University of Missouri Press, 1988, 219 pp. illus. $39.55. Michael Bradshaw. Regions and Regionalism in the United States. Jackson: University Press of Mississippi, 1988, x and 187 pp. David J. Nemeth. The Architecture of Ideology: Neo-Confucian Imprinting on Cheju Island, Korea. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987, xi, 323 pp., maps, photos, diagrams, glossary, references, not indexed, $42.00.  相似文献   
93.
Book reviews     
Selwyn Ilan Troen and Benjamin Pinkus, eds., Organizing Rescue: National Jewish Solidarity in the Modern Period, London, Frank Cass, 1992, pp. xi, 424.

Idith Zertal, From Catastrophe to Power: Jewish Illegal Immigration to Palestine 1945–1948 (Hebrew). Tel Aviv: Am Oved Publishers, 1996. 674 pp.; notes; bibliography; index.

Yoav Gelber, Jewish‐Transjordanian Relations, 1921–48, London: Frank Cass, 1997. 320 pp., glossary, sources and bibliography, index.

Moshe Shemesh, The Palestinian Entity, 1959–1974; Arab Politics and the PLO, Second (Revised) Edition, London: Frank Cass, 1996. xxiii, 433pp., bibliography, index.

Yeshayahu A. Jelinek, ed., Zwischen Moral und Realpolitik: Deutsch‐israelisch Bezeihungen 1945–1965: Eine Doku‐mentensammlung. Gelingen: Bleicher Verlag, 1997. 687 pp.

Angelika Timm, Jewish Claims Against East Germany: Moral Obligations and Pragmatic Policy. Budapest: Central European University Press, 1997, xi + 291pp.  相似文献   
94.
95.
Over the past decades, economic and innovation policy across Europe moved in the direction of creating regional clusters of related firms and institutions. Creating clusters through public policy is risky, complex and costly, however. Moreover, it is not necessary to rely on clusters to stimulate innovation. A differentiated and combined network approach to enhancing innovation and stimulating economic growth may be more efficient and effective, especially though not exclusively in regions lacking clusters. The challenge of such a policy is to mitigate the bottlenecks associated with “global pipeline”, “local buzz” and “stand alone” strategies used by innovative firms and to combine these strategies with a view to their complementarity in terms of knowledge effects. Private and semi-public brokers will be key in the evolving policy, as timely organizational change is crucial for continued innovation, while brokers also need to mitigate governance problems. This requires region-specific knowledge in terms of sectors, life cycles, institutional and socio-cultural factors, and yields spatially differentiated and differentiating adjustment strategies. The role of public policy is to assist in recruiting, provide start-up funding and monitor brokers. With this, policy moves towards a decentralized, process-based, region-specific, spatially diverging and multi-level system of innovation that is geared towards the evolving innovation strategies of firms.  相似文献   
96.
Books reviewed in this article:
Stéphane Courtois et al., The Black Book of Communism: Crimes, Terror, Repression
François Furet, The Passing of an Illusion: The Idea of Communism in the Twentieth Century
Tony Judt, The Burden of Responsibility: Blum, Camus, Aron, and the French Twentieth Century
Michel Dreyfus et al., Le Siècle des communismes  相似文献   
97.
Given the usual neoclassical assumptions of economic rationality, perfect competition, long-term spatial equilibrium, a Thunian context, and perfectly divisible labor and capital, this paper expresses economies of scale in farming in terms of the yield derived from a given level of intensity. If yield increases as farm scale increases, there are economies of scale. If yield decreases, there are diseconomies of scale. The literature on scale economies in agriculture suggests that scale economies accrue from increases in capital inputs, but diseconomies occur as a result of increases in farm area. The models of the spatial structure of agriculture, with farm size included, show the following: 1. Unless there are economies of scale giving way to diseconomies of scale with increases in farm size, no optimal farm area or farm scale can be defined; 2. If the optimal intensity for farming does not vary over space, the optimal farm scale or area should be constant over space; 3. If intensity varies spatially, and if the optimal economies of scale are a function of area only, farm areas should not vary spatially, and sales volume per farm should increase as market access and fertility increase; 4. It is only if intensity varies spatially and optimal scale economies are a function of both area and total quantities of nonland inputs per farm that farm area should increase as distance to market increases or fertility decreases. In this last case, quantities of nonland inputs per farm should also decrease, and usually sales volume per farm should decrease also.  相似文献   
98.
99.
100.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号