首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   3210篇
  免费   166篇
  2020年   34篇
  2019年   61篇
  2018年   101篇
  2017年   79篇
  2016年   135篇
  2015年   76篇
  2014年   78篇
  2013年   781篇
  2012年   89篇
  2011年   118篇
  2010年   89篇
  2009年   103篇
  2008年   73篇
  2007年   85篇
  2006年   84篇
  2005年   44篇
  2004年   44篇
  2003年   51篇
  2002年   36篇
  2001年   63篇
  2000年   50篇
  1999年   57篇
  1998年   49篇
  1997年   42篇
  1996年   39篇
  1995年   32篇
  1994年   20篇
  1993年   46篇
  1992年   33篇
  1991年   22篇
  1990年   32篇
  1989年   36篇
  1988年   27篇
  1987年   35篇
  1986年   29篇
  1985年   32篇
  1984年   25篇
  1983年   48篇
  1982年   36篇
  1981年   33篇
  1980年   33篇
  1979年   28篇
  1978年   34篇
  1977年   37篇
  1976年   32篇
  1975年   30篇
  1974年   27篇
  1973年   25篇
  1972年   29篇
  1971年   24篇
排序方式: 共有3376条查询结果,搜索用时 375 毫秒
91.
In recent articles Evans (1990) and Harrigan and McGregor (1993) (hereafter HM) scrutinized the equilibrium model of migration presented in a 1989 paper by Schachter and Althaus. This model used standard microeconomics to analyze gross interregional migration flows based on the assumption that gross flows are in approximate equilibrium. HM criticized the model as theoretically untenable, while Evans summoned empirical as well as theoretical objections. HM claimed that equilibrium of gross migration flows could be ruled out on theoretical grounds. They argued that the absence of net migration requires that either all regions have equal populations or that unsustainable regional migration propensities must obtain. In fact some moves are inter- and other are intraregional. It does not follow, however, that the number of interregional migrants will be larger for the more populous region. Alternatively, a country could be divided into a large number of small regions that have equal populations. With uniform propensities to move, each of these analytical regions would experience in equilibrium zero net migration. Hence, the condition that net migration equal zero is entirely consistent with unequal distributions of population across regions. The criticisms of Evans were based both on flawed reasoning and on misinterpretation of the results of a number of econometric studies. His reasoning assumed that the existence of demand shifts as found by Goldfarb and Yezer (1987) and Topel (1986) invalidated the equilibrium model. The equilibrium never really obtains exactly, but economic modeling of migration properly begins with a simple equilibrium model of the system. A careful reading of the papers Evans cited in support of his position showed that in fact they affirmed rather than denied the appropriateness of equilibrium modeling. Zero net migration together with nonzero gross migration are not theoretically incompatible with regional heterogeneity of population, wages, or amenities.  相似文献   
92.
93.
94.
95.
96.
97.
The city of Bath     
Sauvain P 《British heritage》1984,6(1):36-46, 73-4
  相似文献   
98.
99.
This paper extends Milk's method for estimating urban population density gradients to general noncircular and asymmetrical urban forms, using Gauss-Legendre quadrature embedded in a Newton-Raphson root finding algorithm. We also examine the sensitivity of the Mills method to measurement errors in the assumptions. Several issues arising from the comparison of analytical, Mills type estimation procedures with statistical procedures are explored, particularly in light of recent work that questions the negative exponential formulation of urban density gradients. We note in particular the influence of secondary population centers as a source of estimation bias.  相似文献   
100.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号