首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   3270篇
  免费   137篇
  2020年   33篇
  2019年   68篇
  2018年   76篇
  2017年   111篇
  2016年   96篇
  2015年   82篇
  2014年   81篇
  2013年   1199篇
  2012年   64篇
  2011年   81篇
  2010年   60篇
  2009年   73篇
  2008年   51篇
  2007年   73篇
  2006年   47篇
  2005年   41篇
  2004年   37篇
  2003年   37篇
  2002年   49篇
  2001年   39篇
  2000年   42篇
  1999年   34篇
  1998年   45篇
  1997年   53篇
  1996年   27篇
  1995年   29篇
  1994年   19篇
  1993年   25篇
  1992年   26篇
  1991年   19篇
  1990年   26篇
  1989年   16篇
  1988年   29篇
  1987年   29篇
  1986年   24篇
  1985年   38篇
  1984年   42篇
  1983年   44篇
  1982年   45篇
  1981年   35篇
  1980年   35篇
  1979年   43篇
  1978年   42篇
  1977年   42篇
  1976年   33篇
  1975年   32篇
  1974年   13篇
  1973年   23篇
  1972年   17篇
  1971年   13篇
排序方式: 共有3407条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
121.
The ideal of a comprehensive higher education planning agency was only partially fulfilled in the 1970's. It was especially limited in its ability to bring independent colleges and universities into statewide planning. The unfulfilled comprehensive statewide planning model makes an attractive case for decentralised decision–making. State planning, usually characterized by the so–called “bureaucratic model,” might be balanced by increased use of an “incentive model.” The work of the state agency would be to encourage and reward fair market competition among the institutions and segments of higher education. Such an approach is based on the conviction that “…intelligent planning can diminish the role of government in the academic and administrative affairs of all sectors, while improving accountability to the public and to the diverse constituencies our institutions serve.”  相似文献   
122.
123.
This paper reports and analyses survey data on the opinions of 353 top position‐holders in business, trade unions, federal and state politics, the Commonwealth Public Service, mass media, national voluntary associations, and major universities and research institutes during the latter half of 1975. Patterns of elite responses to 15 issue sets aggregating 46 separate opinion items are examined. The main focus is on the extent and configuration of elite conflict and consensus over economic policy, foreign and defence policy, industrial relations, social issues, and institutional structure. In general, substantial conflict between left‐of‐centre and right‐of‐centre elites in all major issue areas, save possibly that of social issues, is found. However, the extent of this conflict varies as between specific policies, over which it is relatively small, and the legitimacy or desirability of various group actions and major policy innovations, over which it is quite large. Whether conflict during 1975 was sufficiently great to threaten the fundamental unity of Australian elites is discussed.  相似文献   
124.
It is shown that audience members actively select amongst available programmes on television. This selection is based upon the social role and situational characteristics of the viewer and it is also directly related to the reasons given by viewers for watching television.

Patterns of programme selection are related to three clusters of needs and reasons. The two most important of these are composed of needs relating to information and diversion. The least important cluster is concerned with the self and social contact.

Escape and diversion needs are satisfied by almost any programme; selection is minimal by those viewers expressing these needs. Information needs are best satisfied by news and other informational programmes, while social and self needs are best satisfied by quiz and variety programmes, popular drama and movies.  相似文献   

125.
126.
127.
128.
129.
130.
Mill's unwillingness to support the enforcement of voluntary slavery agreements is problematically related to his strong anti‐paternalism. Working on the assumption that it is too simple to charge him with inconsistency, this paper examines several interpretations of his remarks, and explores some of the deeper motivations that may have influenced his position. Several features of his argument are emphasized: the fact that his opposition is to slavery contracts and not self‐enslavement as such; the weight he allows to ‘the necessities of life’ in determining what freedom‐limiting contracts to enforce; the way in which enforceable slavery agreements would undermine the presumption in favour of liberty; the problematic character of carte blanche consent, and the possibility this raises that enforcement could make the law a party to criminable harm. Although Mill's argument is too cryptic to be persuasive, it is too suggestive to be given the off‐handed treatment often meted out by his commentators.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号